The main pressure on
rural lands emanates from urban
encroachment. Changing needs and trends encourage urban dwellers to move
outward to rural towns, carrying with them their urban lifestyles and
tendencies. Businesses follow when critical mass is reached to
sustain high levels of demand
for products and services. The rural towns, somewhere along the
process, lose their character and slowly become urbanised.
Since, urban-related land uses can offer returns way above what
can be realise if lands are used in farming, farmlands
are indeed susceptible to the pressure. Moreover, the changing
policies as regards land-use creates and/or reinforces what planners call the
"impermanence syndrome", which causes farmers
to resort to low-input farm practices and to ultimately give
up farming.
Non-sustainable land
uses can likewise exert additional pressure to rural
lands. Extractive industries for instance can realise massive
profits compared to other more traditional uses. These pressures
are actually external to the farm. A number of economic factors,
which internally affect farm
operations, may be the real culprits that exacerbate the susceptibility of these farms.
The economics of time, for
instance, may assist in weakening the intent of farmers to continue with
production. Investments in primary production
are long-term investments (Cook, 1994). Realization of
returns can take a long time compared to secondary
sectors like manufacturing and processing. For
instance, investments in backyard piggeries can take some years to
break even and fully recoup the initial capital investments.
Given this fact, and while at the same
time, the farmers do not feel secure about the land-use policies which
define the security of tenure of farming in a given area, the
tendency to give up the farm is strengthened.
Changes in the national
economy can also affect the viability of farms (Cook, 1994). As the economy
expands, it is often accompanied by increases in real wage rates,
which means that labor becomes more expensive to employ in
farming. Moreover, real prices may also increase
such that the price of farm products sometimes
can not keep pace with the rise in costs of farm inputs thus
there is a net decrease in real farm incomes.
A natural fall in the
inherent productivity of bio-physical resources can also
occur as a result of intense use and degradation (Cook,
1994). The usual tendency of farmers is to turn to
better technology which more often would entail additional capital outlays.
Health risks and negative environmental effects may
also be faced if farmers decide to intensify their usage of
farm chemicals to boost productivity.
Cyclical and random changes
in the prices of goods and input costs are also factors which can adversely
affect the financial standing of farms (Cook, 1994). Changes in prices
of goods may be caused by many factors. Financial
deregulation could increase volatility of
interest rates and currency exchange rates, which in turn,
increased the fluctuations
in the prices of farm goods. The
restructuring of former East Bloc countries from 1992 following the
fall of communism in Europe changed demand patterns for
several farm commodities in Asia and Australia. Trade and protectionist policies of major economies could also inhibit some farm products to enter those markets.
Lastly, natural
calamities and changes in weather patters as what is happening now can spell disastrous effects to the farms' finances performance.
The interplay of these
factors complicates the farming predicament. It may be noted that except
for natural events, all others of the above-cited factors are economic in nature.
They have a singular effect on the farming operations
and that is the weakening of the farm's
economic viability and financial standing. The financial
difficulty faced by farmers make them very prone to the external
pressures e.g. the monetary benefits that developers and speculators
can offer in exchange for their lands.
There are only
two options for farmers to choose from. Either
they cling to their farms amidst economic difficulties or
simply sell out. Farmers tend to cling to their farms
for a number of reasons, among others, because the farm
is synonymous to home, due to peer pressure, the availability of off-farm income
which enable them to cross-subsidise farm losses, and the notion
that to leave the farm is to fall into the poverty trap, that is,
they have no better place to go and therefore they will have to continue
farming by all means. When they decide to continue with
farming, farmers may need to resort to
cost-cutting, diversification and partial sale of other
assets. Those who are eligible turn to government for assistance.
(from R. Azanza's academic paper)